Quoted: Greys Sošić in Restaurant Business
Sošić, E. Morgan Stanley chair in business administration, tells Restaurant Business that a warming planet greatly affects restaurant supply chain management.
Greys Sošić holds a PhD from the University of British Columbia, and a master's and a bachelor's degree from the University of Zagreb, Croatia. Her research interests include supply chain management, sustainability, competition and cooperation in supply chains, with emphasis on coalition stability. Her work has been published in journals such as Management Science, Operations Research, M&SOM, POMS. Greys is an Associate Editor for Operations Research and POMS, and a Department Editor for IISE Transactions. She has received Dean's Awards for Research Excellence and IISE Transactions Design & Manufacturing Best Paper Award. She has been teaching courses on supply chain management, sustainability, and sourcing.
Areas of Expertise
Programs
Departments
Centers + Institutes
INSIGHT + ANALYSIS
Quoted: Greys Sošić in Restaurant Business
Sošić, E. Morgan Stanley chair in business administration, tells Restaurant Business that a warming planet greatly affects restaurant supply chain management.
Quoted: Greys Sošić in Los Angeles Business Journal
Sošić, senior vice dean of faculty and academic affairs and professor of data sciences and operation, speaks to LA Business Journal about the risks and benefits of centralized inventory business models in supply chain management.
Quoted: Marshall Experts Assess Recent EPA Tailpipe Regulations
GREYS SOŠIĆ, NICK VYAS, and SHON HIATT offer thoughts on what follows in terms of auto companies, supply chain, and energy independence.
Quoted: Greys Sošić by FactCheck.org
Greys Sošić, DSO Department Chair, is quoted by Factcheck.org regarding recent shortages and supply chain signals.
NEWS + EVENTS
USC Marshall Announces Launch of Business of Blockchain Initiative
Strategic investment accelerates teaching, research, and industry engagement, shaping the impact of decentralized technologies across sectors.
USC Marshall Faculty Honored in Chair Installation Ceremony
Fourteen high-achieving faculty were installed with endowed chairs.
12th Annual Global Supply Chain Summit Gathers Industry and Academic Leaders
Speakers and attendees tackled the future of the supply chain, from sustainability to the integration of artificial intelligence at the Global Supply Chain Excellence Summit.
Marshall Faculty Publications, Awards, and Honors: March 2024
We are proud to highlight the amazing Marshall faculty who have received awards, recognitions, and publications for their groundbreaking work.
USC Marshall Faculty Hiring Initiative Advances Toward Goal of Gender Parity and Diversity
Marshall builds organizational diversity with focus on underrepresented scholars.
Sustainability and Geopolitics: The Global Supply Chain Institute Tackles The World’s Most Pressing Issues
Professors Nick Vyas and Greys Sošić believe the supply chain institute has more to teach than turning a profit.
Marshall Faculty Publications, Awards, and Honors: May 2023 and Year-End Roundup
We are thrilled to congratulate our faculty on recently accepted and published research, 2022-2023 teaching and research awards, and new chair appointments.
Marshall Phd Student Honored With University Award for Teaching Assistants
Junxiong Yin, a fifth-year PhD student in Marshall’s Department of Data Sciences and Operations, has been awarded a University Outstanding Teaching Assistant Award.
Data's Time to Shine
Marshall’s Data Sciences and Operations department has stellar year, racking up grants, research awards and other honors.
RESEARCH + PUBLICATIONS
Is it feasible to build desalination plants for the co-production of salt and freshwater from U.S. seawater that could lead to a restructuring of supply chains for salt imports? As it is predicted that climate change will increase water stress worldwide, an increasing number of countries are using desalination plants to generate freshwater. In most such cases, residual concentrates must be disposed of, and the disposal cost is increasing as countries are becoming more environmentally conscious. Selective salt recovery can help to alleviate this issue, as it reduces the need for concentrate disposal and generates additional revenue.
To gain some insights into the costs and benefits of co-production plants, we have collected data on current desalination practices and salt imports in the U.S., along with the manufacturing costs and energy requirements for co-production plants. We have used this data to build an optimization model to determine an optimal number and location of co-production plants in the U.S. and their potential markets for the sale of co-produced salt. In our analysis, we have considered a different total number of co-production facilities, and for each configuration we evaluated the resulting net water cost and carbon emissions impact. Our results indicate that there exists the potential for building several co-production plants in the U.S. that would be both financially competitive with existing desalination plants and lead to a reduction in carbon emissions. This information might be of use to both governments and businesses when they make decisions about the type of desalination facilities built and the implemented “polluter pays” policies.
Linking of emission permit markets allows participants in different systems to purchase allowances from each other for the purposes of domestic compliance. As increasing efficiency in reducing carbon emissions is critical for achieving the goals of the Paris Agreement, it is necessary to understand the factors that can impact the stability of linked markets, and what can be done to induce formation of larger and more efficient linked markets.
In their recent paper, Doda, Quemin, and Taschini (2019) studied efficiency gains generated in multilateral linkings between permit markets, and concluded that although the linking of all jurisdictions maximizes efficiency gains, it is not likely to emerge as it is not the most preferred option by all participants. In this paper, we formulate the linking problem as a cooperative game and show that linking of all jurisdictions satisfies stability criteria as defined by the core of the underlying game. Thus, no subset of jurisdictions would benefit from creating their separate linked market, and the gains will be maximized in the all-inclusive emission permit market.
We then extend our analysis to arbitrary coalition structures and farsightedness level and analyze the stable linking of emission permit markets between five jurisdictions: Australia, Canada, the EU, South Korea, and the U.S. Due to asymmetry between different jurisdictions, our results indicate that the most likely stable configuration includes two linked markets: a market that links Australia, the EU, and the U.S., and another in which Canada is linked with South Korea. This scenario leaves about 15% of potential efficiency gains unrealized. To mitigate this issue, we suggest that efficiency gains from market linkage be allocated according to the Shapley value, which takes into account contributions of different jurisdictions to common markets. If the Shapley value allocation is used, our results suggest that we would see stable linking of all five jurisdictions and thus increase the efficiency of market linkage.
In a non-negative profit game that possesses a Population Monotonic Allocation Scheme (PMAS), being a member of a larger coalition implies that your profit cannot decrease. In this paper, we refer to such games as PMAS profit games. As population monotonicity is a nice and desirable property that encourages formation of larger coalitions and implies stability of the grand coalition, we explore if this special feature of PMAS games can help in identifying additional stable coalition structures under different stability concepts in cooperative game---namely, core partitions, the von Neumann--Morgenstern (vNM) stable set, the largest consistent set, and the equilibrium process of coalition formation (EPCF)---and in developing relationships between coalition structures that are stable under these different stability concepts.
We first define two special classes of players for PMAS profit games---extreme and strong players---and use them to develop an algorithm for construction of stable (core) partitions. We also use extreme players to identify absorbing states for equilibrium processes of coalition formation with high level of farsightedness.
We then explore the impact of population monotonicity on the relationship between stable coalition structures under abovementioned stability concepts. While we are able to obtain some results related to stability of the grand coalition and to establish relationships between stable coalition structures under different stability notions that are consistent with the existing body of knowledge, population monotonicity in general does not add enough for strengthening of the existing results. However, we are able to show a couple of more general result that hold for arbitrary cooperative TU profit games. That is, we show that the members of vNM farsighted stable sets are core partitions, and that core partitions are members of a vNM stable sets. Moreover, we show that the members of vNM farsighted stable sets are EPCF-stable partitions.
We study a special class of cooperative games with transferable utility (TU), called m-attribute games. Every player in an m-attribute game is endowed with a vector of attributes that can be combined in an additive fashion; that is, if players form a coalition, the attribute vector of this coalition is obtained by adding the attributes of its members. Another fundamental feature of m-attribute games is that their characteristic function is defined by a continuous attribute function—the value of a coalition depends only on evaluation of on the attribute vector possessed by the coalition, and not on the identity of coalition members. This class of games encompasses many well-known examples, such as queueing games and economic lot-sizing games. We believe that by studying attribute function and its properties, instead of specific examples of games, we are able to develop a common platform for studying different situations and obtain more general results with wider applicability. In this paper, we first show the relationship between nonemptiness of the core and identification of attribute prices that can be used to calculate core allocations. We then derive necessary and sufficient conditions under which every m-attribute game embedded in attribute function has a nonempty core, and a set of necessary and sufficient conditions that should satisfy for the embedded game to be convex. We also develop several sufficient conditions for nonemptiness of the core of m-attribute games, which are easier to check, and show how to find a core allocation when these conditions hold. Finally, we establish natural connections between TU games and m-attribute games.
Because greenhouse-gas (GHG) emissions from the supply chains of just the 2,500 largest global corporations account for more than 20% of global emissions, rationalizing emissions in supply chains could make an important contribution toward meeting the global CO2 emission-reduction targets agreed upon in the 2015 Paris Climate Agreement. Accordingly, in this paper, we consider supply chains with joint production of GHG emissions, operating under either a carbon-tax regime, wherein a regulator levies a penalty on the emissions generated by the firms in the supply chain, or an internal carbon-pricing scheme. Supply chain leaders, such as Walmart, are assumed to be environmentally motivated to induce their suppliers to abate their emissions. We adopt a cooperative game-theory methodology to derive a footprint-balanced scheme for reapportioning the total carbon emissions amongst the firms in the supply chain. This emission responsibility-allocation scheme, which is the Shapley value of an associated cooperative game, is shown to have several desirable characteristics. In particular, (i) it is transparent and easy to compute; (ii) when the abatement-cost functions of the firms are private information, it incentivizes suppliers to exert pollution-abatement efforts that, among all footprint-balanced allocation schemes, minimize the maximum deviation from the socially optimal pollution level; and (iii) the Shapley value is the unique allocation mechanism satisfying certain contextually desirable properties.